Profit and loss sharing

Profit and Loss Sharing (also called PLS or "participatory" banking[1]) is a method of finance used by Islamic financial or Shariah-complaint institutions to comply with the religious prohibition on interest on loans that many Muslims subscribe to. There are two varieties of Profit and Loss Sharing used by Islamic banks -- Mudarabah (مضاربة) and Musharakah (مشاركة or شركة ).[2]

The profits and losses shared in PLS are those of a business enterprise or person which/who has borrowed money from the Islamic bank/financial institution. As the loan is repaid, the lender collects some agreed upon percentage of the profits (or deducts if there are losses) along with the principal of the loan[Note 1], unlike a conventional bank which collects some fixed rate of interest along with the principal of the loan.[3] Also unlike conventional banking, the PLS bank acts as a capital partner (in the mudarabah form of PLS) serving as an intermediary between the depositor on one side and the entrepreneur/borrower on the other.[4] The intention is to promote "the concept of participation in a transaction backed by real assets, utilising the funds at risk on a profit-and-loss-sharing basis".[2]

Profit-and-loss-sharing is one of "two basic categories" of Islamic financing,[2] the other being "debt-based contracts" (or "debt-like instruments")[5] such as murabaha, istisna'a, salam and leasing, which involve the "purchase and hire of goods or assets and services on a fixed-return basis".[2] While some (such as Mohammad Najatuallah Siddiqui) hoped PLS would be the primary mode of Islamic finance, fixed return financing now far exceeds PLS in the Islamic financing industry.[6]

Background

One of the pioneers of Islamic banking, Mohammad Najatuallah Siddiqui, suggested a two-tier model as the basis of a riba-free banking, with mudarabah being the primary mode,[4] supplemented by a number of fixed-return models—mark-up (murabaha), leasing (ijara), cash advances for the purchase of agricultural produce (salam) and cash advances for the manufacture of assets (istisna'), etc. In practice, the fixed-return models -- in particular murabaha model—have become the bank's favourites,[6] as long-term financing with profit-and-loss-sharing mechanisms has turned out to be more risky and costly than the long term or medium-term lending of the conventional banks.[7]

Mudarabah

Mudarabah is a partnership where one partner (rabb-ul-mal) gives money to another (mudarib) for investing in a commercial enterprise. The rabb-ul-mal party provides 100 percent of the capital and the mudarib party provides its specialized knowledge to invest the capital and manage the investment project. Profits generated are shared between the parties according to a pre-agreed ratio. If there is a loss, rabb-ul-mal will lose his capital, and the mudarib party will lose the time and effort invested in the project. The profit is usually shared 50%-50% or 60%-40% for rabb ul mal-mudarib.

Further, Mudaraba is venture capital funding of an entrepreneur who provides labor while financing is provided by the bank so that both profit and risk are shared. Such participatory arrangements between capital and labor reflect the Islamic view that the borrower must not bear all the risk/cost of a failure, resulting in a balanced distribution of income and not allowing the lender to monopolize the economy.

Mudaraba contracts are used in inter-bank lending. The borrowing and lending banks negotitate the PLS ratio and contracts may be as short as overnight and as long as one year.[8]

Mudarabah contracts may be restricted or unrestricted.

A variation of mudarabah that has caused some complaint is one that replaces Profit and Loss Sharing between depositor and bank with Profit Sharing—the losses being all the problem of the depositors. Instead of both the bank and its depositors being the owners of the capital (rabb al-mal), and the entrepreneur the mudarib, the bank and the entrepreneur are now both mudarib, and if there are any losses after meeting the overhead and operational expenses, they are passed on to depositors. One critic (Ibrahim Warde) has dubbed this `Islamic moral hazard` in which the banks are able `to privatise the profits and socialize the losses`.[11][12]

Another critic (M.A. Khan), has questioned the mudarabah's underlying rationale of fairness to the mudarib. Rather than fixed interest lending being unfair to the entrepreneur/borrower, Khan asks if it isn't unfair to the rabb al-mal (provider of finance) to "get a return only if the results of investment are profitable", since by providing funds they have done their part to make the investment possible, while the actions of entrepreneur/borrower -- their inspiration, competence, diligence, probity, etc. -- have the power (at least in part) to make the investment profitable or a failure.[13]

Musharakah

Musharakah is a joint enterprise in which all the partners share the profit or loss of the joint venture.[14] The two (or more) parties that contribute capital to a business divide the net profit and loss on a pro rata basis.

Musharakah is often used in investment projects, letters of credit, and the purchase or real estate or property. In the case of real estate or property, the bank assesses an imputed rent and will share it as agreed in advance.[15] All providers of capital are entitled to participate in management, but not necessarily required to do so. The profit is distributed among the partners in pre-agreed ratios, while the loss is borne by each partner strictly in proportion to respective capital contributions. This concept is distinct from fixed-income investing (i.e. issuance of loans).[16]

Musharaka is an approach used in business transactions. Islamic banks lend their money to companies by issuing floating rate interest loans. The floating rate of interest is pegged to the company's individual rate of return. Thus, the bank's profit on the loan is equal to a certain percentage of the company's profits. Once the principal amount of the loan is repaid, the profit-sharing arrangement is concluded.[17]

Differences

According to Mufti Taqi Usmani, a mudarabah arrangement differs from the musharakah in several ways:

Promises and challenges

Profit and Loss Sharing has been called "the main justification" for,[5] or even "the very purpose" of the Islamic finance and banking movement"[21] and the "basic and foremost characteristic of Islamic financing".[22]

One proponent, Taqi Usmani, envisioned it transforming economies by

Usmani notes that some non-Muslim economists[Note 2] have supported development of equity markets in "areas of finance currently served by debt"[25] (though they do not support banning interest on loans).

While it was originally envisioned (at least in mudarabah form), as "the basis of a riba-free banking",[4] with fixed-return financial models only filling in as supplements, it is those fixed-return products whose assets-under-management now far exceed those in profit-loss-sharing modes.[6]

One study from 2000-2006 found PLS financing in the "leading Islamic banks" had declined to only 6.34% of total financing, down from 17.34% in 1994-6. "Debt-based contracts" or "debt-like instruments" were far more popular in the sample. 54.42% of financing was on the basis of murabaha, 16.31% on the basis of ijara and 5.60% on the basis of salam and istisna during 2004-6.[5][26] Another source (Suliman Hamdan Albalawi) decries the departure of PLS techniques as "a core principle of Islamic banking" in Saudi Arabia and Egypt,[27] In Malaysia a study found the share of musharaka financing declined from 1.4% in 2000 to 0.2% in 2006.[28][29]

This "mass-scale adoption" of fixed-return modes of finance by Islamic financial institutions has been criticized by shariah scholars and pioneers of Islamic finance like Mohammad Najatuallah Siddiqui, Mohammad Umer Chapra, Muhammad Taqi Usmani and Khurshid Ahmad who have "argued vehemently that moving away from musharaka and mudaraba would simply defeat the very purpose of the Islamic finance movement".

Explanations

Critics have in turn criticized PLS advocates for remaining "oblivious to the fact" that the reason PLS has not been widely adopted "lies in its inefficiency" (Muhammad Akram Khan),[21] and their "consequence-insensitive" way of thinking, assuming that "ample supply" of PLS "instruments will create their own demand" (Nawab Haider Naqvi), consumer disinterest notwithstanding.[30]

Many explanations have been offered as to why use of PLS instruments has declined to almost negligible proportions:

Reply

Taqi Usmani states that the problems of PLS would be eliminating by banning interest and requiring all banks to be run on a "pure Islamic pattern with careful support from the Central Bank and government."[40] The danger of dishonesty by borrowers/clients would be solved by

  1. requiring every company/corporation to use a credit rating;
  2. implementing a "well designed" system of auditing.[40]


See also

References

Notes

  1. The money originally invested or loaned, on which basis interest and returns are calculated
  2. James Robertson and John Tomlinson[24]

Citations

  1. Çetin, Hüseyin (August 2014). "Econometric Modeling of Turkish Participatory Banks Deposits" (PDF). International Journal of Trade, Economics and Finance. 5 (4): 322. doi:10.7763/IJTEF.2014.V5.391. Retrieved 16 August 2015.
  2. 1 2 3 4 "Islamic Banking. Profit-and-Loss Sharing". Institute of Islamic Banking and Insurance. Retrieved 15 August 2015.
  3. "PROFIT AND LOSS SHARING Definition". VentureLine. Retrieved 16 August 2015.
  4. 1 2 3 Curtis, Mallet-Prevost, Colt & Mosle LLP (3 July 2012). "Islamic Banking: A Brief Introduction". Oman Law Blog. Curtis, Mallet-Prevost, Colt & Mosle LLP. Retrieved 10 August 2015.
  5. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.322-3
  6. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.275
  7. Yousef, Tarik M. (2004). "The Murabaha Syndrome in Islamic Finance: Laws, Institutions, and Politics". In Henry, Clement M.; Wilson, Rodney. THE POLITICS OF ISLAMIC FINANCE (PDF). Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press,. Retrieved 5 August 2015.
  8. Jamaldeen, Faleel. Islamic Finance for Dummies (ebook). p. 387.
  9. 1 2 3 Usmani, Introduction to Islamic Finance, 1998: p.32
  10. 1 2 3 El Tiby Ahmed, Amr Mohamed (2011). Islamic Banking: How to Manage Risk and Improve Profitability. Wiley. p. 54. Retrieved 23 July 2016.
  11. Warde, Islamic finance in the global economy, 2000: p.164
  12. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.321
  13. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.232-3
  14. 1 2 3 Usmani, Introduction to Islamic Finance, 1998: pp.17-36
  15. Nomani, Farhad; Rahnema, Ali (1994). Islamic Economic Systems. New Jersey: Zed books limited. pp. 99–101. ISBN 1-85649-058-0.
  16. "THE DECLINING BALANCE CO-OWNERSHIP PROGRAM AN OVERVIEW" (PDF). Guidance Residential. 21 October 2002. Retrieved 6 September 2016.
  17. "Islamic banks commercial transactions". Financial Islam - Islamic Finance. Retrieved 12 July 2016.
  18. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 "Mudarabah". Concepts in Islamic Economics and Finance. Retrieved 17 August 2015.
  19. Usmani, Introduction to Islamic Finance, 1998: p.31
  20. Musharakah & Mudarabah By Mufti Taqi Usmani | Limited Liability| central-mosque.com
  21. 1 2 Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.325
  22. Usmani, Historic Judgment on Interest, 1999: para 204
  23. Usmani, Historic Judgment on Interest, 1999: para 205
  24. Usmani, Historic Judgment on Interest, 1999: para 150, 168, 204, 205
  25. Usmani, Historic Judgment on Interest, 1999: para 204, 205
  26. Khan M. Mansoor and M. Ishaq Bhatti. 2008. Developments in Islamic banking: The case of Pakistan. Houndsmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, p.49
  27. Albalawi, Suliman Hamdan (September 2006). "Banking System in Islamic Countries: Saudi Arabia and Egypt. A Dissertation Submitted to the School of Law and the Committee on Graduate Studies of Stanford University" (PDF). law.stanford.edu. Retrieved 10 April 2015.
  28. (Z Hasan, Fifty years of Malaysian economic development: Policies and achievements, Review of Islamic Economics, 11 (2) (2007))
  29. Asutay, Mehmet. 2007. Conceptualization of the second best solution in overcoming the social failure of Islamic banking and finance: Examining the overpowering of the homoislamicus by homoeconomicus. IIUM Journal of Economics and Management 15 (2) 173
  30. Naqvi, S.N.H. 2000. Islamic banking: An evaluation. IIUM Journal of Economics and Management 8 (1) 41-70
  31. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.276, 277 18.1, 18.2
  32. 1 2 Balala, Maha-Hanaan (2011). Islamic finance and law. London and New York: I.B. Tauris.
  33. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.278-9
  34. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.326-7
  35. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Dar, Humayon A. and J.R. Presley (2000-01. Lack of profit loss sharing in Islamic banking: Management and control imbalance., Economics research paper 024. Leicester: Loughborough University. 5-6)
  36. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.278, 18.3
  37. 1 2 3 4 Iqbal, Munawar and Philip Molyneux. 2005. Thirty years of Islamic banking: History, performance and prospects. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. p.136
  38. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.324
  39. Khan, What Is Wrong with Islamic Economics?, 2013: p.282, 18.6.6
  40. 1 2 Usmani, Historic Judgment on Interest, 1999: para 216

Books and journal articles

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 12/1/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.